Where have all the criminals gone
In 1966, one year after NicolaeCeaus¸escu became the Communist
dictator of Romania, he made abortion illegal. “The fetus is the property
of the entire society,” he proclaimed. “Anyone who avoids having
children is a deserter who abandons the laws of national continuity.”
Such grandiose declarations were commonplace during Ceaus
¸escu’s reign, for his master plan—to create a nation worthy of the
New Socialist Man—was an exercise in grandiosity. He built palaces
for himself while alternately brutalizing and neglecting his citizens.
Abandoning agriculture in favor of manufacturing, he forced many of
the nation’s rural dwellers into unheated apartment buildings. He
gave government positions to forty family members including his
wife, Elena, who required forty homes and a commensurate supply of
fur and jewels. Madame Ceaus¸escu, known officially as the Best
Mother Romania Could Have, was not particularly maternal. “The
worms never get satisfied, regardless of how much food you give
them,” she said when Romanians complained about the food shortwe learned not to be afraid from our children,” he said. “Most were
aged thirteen to twenty.” A few days after the massacre in Timisoara,
Ceaus¸escu gave a speech in Bucharest before one hundred thousand
people. Again the young people were out in force. They shouted
downCeaus¸escu with cries of “Timisoara!” and “Down with the
murderers!” His time had come. He and Elena tried to escape the
country with $1 billion, but they were captured, given a crude trial,
and, on Christmas Day, executed by firing squad.
Of all the Communist leaders deposed in the years bracketing the
collapse of the Soviet Union, only NicolaeCeaus¸escu met a violent
death. It should not be overlooked that his demise was precipitated in
large measure by the youth of Romania—a great number of whom,
were it not for his abortion ban, would never have been born at all.
The story of abortion in Romania might seem an odd way to begin
telling the story of American crime in the 1990s. But it’s not. In one
important way, the Romanian abortion story is a reverse image of the
American crime story. The point of overlap was on that Christmas
Day of 1989, when NicolaeCeaus¸escu learned the hard way—with a
bullet to the head—that his abortion ban had much deeper implications
than he knew.
On that day, crime was just about at its peak in the United States.
In the previous fifteen years, violent crime had risen 80 percent. It was
crime that led the nightly news and the national conversation.
When the crime rate began falling in the early 1990s, it did so with
such speed and suddenness that it surprised everyone. It took some
experts many years to even recognize that crime was falling, so confident
had they been of its continuing rise. Long after crime had
peaked, in fact, some of them continued to predict ever darker scenarios.
But the evidence was irrefutable: the long and brutal spike incrime was moving in the opposite direction, and it wouldn’t stop until
the crime rate had fallen back to the levels of forty years earlier.
Now the experts hustled to explain their faulty forecasting. The
criminologist James Alan Fox explained that his warning of a “bloodbath”
was in fact an intentional overstatement. “I never said there
would be blood flowing in the streets,” he said, “but I used strong
terms like ‘bloodbath’ to get people’s attention. And it did. I don’t
apologize for using alarmist terms.” (If Fox seems to be offering a distinction
without a difference—“bloodbath” versus “blood flowing in
the streets”—we should remember that even in retreat mode, experts
can be self-serving.)
After the relief had settled in, after people remembered how to go
about their lives without the pressing fear of crime, there arose a natural
question: just where did all those criminals go?
At one level, the answer seemed puzzling. After all, if none of the
criminologists, police officials, economists, politicians, or others who
traffic in such matters had foreseen the crime decline, how could they
suddenlyidentifyitscauses?
But this diverse army of experts now marched out a phalanx of
hypotheses to explain the drop in crime. A great many newspaper
articles would be written on the subject. Their conclusions often
hinged on which expert had most recently spoken to which reporter.
Here, ranked by frequency of mention, are the crime-drop explanations
cited in articles published from 1991 to 2001 in the ten largestcirculation
papers in the LexisNexis database:
CRIME-DROP EXPLANATION NUMBER OF CITATIONS
1. Innovative policing strategies 52
2. Increased reliance on prisons 47
3. Changes in crack and other drug markets 33
4. Aging of the population 32
5. Tougher gun-control laws 32
6. Strong economy 28
7. Increased number of police 26
8. All other explanations (increased use of 34
capital punishment, concealed-weapons
laws, gun buybacks, and others)
If you are the sort of person who likes guessing games, you may
wish to spend the next few moments pondering which of the preceding
explanations seem to have merit and which don’t. Hint: of the
seven major explanations on the list, only three can be shown to have
contributed to the drop in crime. The others are, for the most part,
figments of someone’s imagination, self-interest, or wishful thinking.
Further hint: one of the greatest measurable causes of the crime drop
does not appear on the list at all, for it didn’t receive a single newspaper
mention.
Let’s begin with a fairly uncontroversial one: the strong economy. The
decline in crime that began in the early 1990s was accompanied by a
blistering national economy and a significant drop in unemployment.
It might seem to follow that the economy was a hammer that helped
beat down crime. But a closer look at the data destroys this theory. It
is true that a stronger job market may make certain crimes relatively
less attractive. But that is only the case for crimes with a direct financial
motivation—burglary, robbery, and auto theft—as opposed to violent
crimes like homicide, assault, and rape. Moreover, studies have
shown that an unemployment decline of 1 percentage point accounts
for a 1 percent drop in nonviolent crime. During the 1990s, the unemployment
rate fell by 2 percentage points; nonviolent crime,meanwhile, fell by roughly 40 percent. But an even bigger flaw in the
strong-economy theory concerns violent crime. Homicide fell at a
greater rate during the 1990s than any other sort of crime, and a number
of reliable studies have shown virtually no link between the economy
and violent crime. This weak link is made even weaker by
glancing back to a recent decade, the 1960s, when the economy went
on a wild growth spurt—as did violent crime. So while a strong 1990s
economy might have seemed, on the surface, a likely explanation for
the drop in crime, it almost certainly didn’t affect criminal behavior in
any significant way.
Unless, that is, “the economy” is construed in a broader sense—as
a means to build and maintain hundreds of prisons. Let’s now consider
another crime-drop explanation: increased reliance on prisons. It
might help to start by flipping the crime question around. Instead of
wondering what made crime fall, think about this: why had it risen so
dramatically in the first place?During the first half of the twentieth century, the incidence of violent
crime in the United States was, for the most part, fairly steady. But
in the early 1960s, it began to climb. In retrospect, it is clear that one
of the major factors pushing this trend was a more lenient justice system.
Conviction rates declined during the 1960s, and criminals who
were convicted served shorter sentences. This trend was driven in part
by an expansion in the rights of people accused of crimes—a long
overdue expansion, some would argue. (Others would argue that the
expansion went too far.) At the same time, politicians were growing
increasingly softer on crime—“for fear of sounding racist,” as the
economist Gary Becker has written, “since African-Americans and
Hispanics commit a disproportionate share of felonies.” So if you were
the kind of person who might want to commit a crime, the incentives
were lining up in your favor: a slimmer likelihood of being convicted
and, if convicted, a shorter prison term. Because criminals respond to
incentives as readily as anyone, the result was a surge in crime.It took some time, and a great deal of political turmoil, but these
incentives were eventually curtailed. Criminals who would have previously
been set free—for drug-related offenses and parole revocation
in particular—were instead locked up. Between 1980 and 2000, there
was a fifteenfold increase in the number of people sent to prison on
drug charges. Many other sentences, especially for violent crime, were
lengthened. The total effect was dramatic. By 2000, more than two
million people were in prison, roughly four times the number as of
1972. Fully half of that increase took place during the 1990s.The evidence linking increased punishment with lower crime rates
is very strong. Harsh prison terms have been shown to act as both deterrent
(for the would-be criminal on the street) and prophylactic (for
the would-be criminal who is already locked up). Logical as this may
sound, some criminologists have fought the logic. A 1977 academic
study called “On Behalf of a Moratorium on Prison Construction”
noted that crime rates tend to be high when imprisonment rates are
high, and concluded that crime would fall if imprisonment rates
could only be lowered. (Fortunately, jailers did not suddenly turn
loose their wards and sit back waiting for crime to fall. As the political
scientist John J. DiIulio Jr. later commented, “Apparently, it takes a
Ph.D. in criminology to doubt that keeping dangerous criminals incarcerated
cuts crime.”)
The “Moratorium” argument rests on a fundamental confusion of
correlation and causality. Consider a parallel argument. The mayor of
a city sees that his citizens celebrate wildly when their team wins the
World Series. He is intrigued by this correlation but, like the “Moratorium”
author, fails to see the direction in which the correlation runs.
So the following year, the mayor decrees that his citizens start celebrating
the World Series before the first pitch is thrown—an act that, in
his confused mind, will ensure a victory.
There are certainly plenty of reasons to dislike the huge surge in
the prison population. Not everyone is pleased that such a significantfraction of Americans, especially black Americans, live behind bars.
Nor does prison even begin to address the root causes of crime, which
are diverse and complex. Lastly, prison is hardly a cheap solution: it
costs about $25,000 a year to keep someone incarcerated. But if the
goal here is to explain the drop in crime in the 1990s, imprisonment
is certainly one of the key answers. It accounts for roughly one-third
of the drop in crime.
Another crime-drop explanation is often cited in tandem with imprisonment:
the increased use of capital punishment. The number of executions
in the United States quadrupled between the 1980s and the
1990s, leading many people to conclude—in the context of a debate
that has been going on for decades—that capital punishment helped
drive down crime. Lost in the debate, however, are two important facts.
First, given the rarity with which executions are carried out in this
country and the long delays in doing so, no reasonable criminal
should be deterred by the threat of execution. Even though capital
punishment quadrupled within a decade, there were still only 478 executions
in the entire United States during the 1990s. Any parent
who has ever said to a recalcitrant child, “Okay, I’m going to count to
ten and this time I’m really going to punish you,” knows the difference
between deterrent and empty threat. New York State, for instance,
has not as of this writing executed a single criminal since
reinstituting its death penalty in 1995. Even among prisoners ondeath row, the annual execution rate is only 2 percent—compared
with the 7 percent annual chance of dying faced by a member of the
Black Gangster Disciple Nation crack gang. If life on death row is
safer than life on the streets, it’s hard to believe that the fear of execution
is a driving force in a criminal’s calculus. Like the $3 fine for latearriving
parents at the Israeli day-care centers, the negative incentive
of capital punishment simply isn’t serious enough for a criminal to
change his behavior.The second flaw in the capital punishment argument is even more
obvious. Assume for a moment that the death penalty is a deterrent.
How much crime does it actually deter? The economist Isaac Ehrlich,
in an oft-cited 1975 paper, put forth an estimate that is generally considered
optimistic: executing 1 criminal translates into 7 fewer homicides
that the criminal might have committed. Now do the math. In
1991, there were 14 executions in the United States; in 2001, there
were 66. According to Ehrlich’s calculation, those 52 additional executions
would have accounted for 364 fewer homicides in 2001—not
a small drop, to be sure, but less than 4 percent of the actual decrease
in homicides that year. So even in a death penalty advocate’s best-case
scenario, capital punishment could explain only one twenty-fifth of
the drop in homicides in the 1990s. And because the death penalty is
rarely given for crimes other than homicide, its deterrent effect cannot
account for a speck of decline in other violent crimes.
It is extremely unlikely, therefore, that the death penalty, as currently
practiced in the United States, exerts any real influence on
crime rates. Even many of its onetime supporters have come to this
conclusion. “I feel morally and intellectually obligated simply to concede
that the death penalty experiment has failed,” said U.S. Supreme
Court Justice Harry A. Blackmun in 1994, nearly twenty years after
he had voted for its reinstatement. “I no longer shall tinker with the
machinery of death.”
So it wasn’t capital punishment that drove crime down nor was it the
booming economy. But higher rates of imprisonment did have a lot to
do with it. All those criminals didn’t march into jail by themselves, of
course. Someone had to investigate the crime, catch the bad guy, and
put together the case that would get him convicted. Which naturally
leads to a related pair of crime-drop explanations:Innovative policing strategies
Increased number of police
Let’s address the second one first. The number of police officers per
capita in the United States rose about 14 percent during the 1990s.
Does merely increasing the number of police, however, reduce crime?
The answer would seem obvious—yes—but proving that answer isn’t
so easy. That’s because when crime is rising, people clamor for protection,
and invariably more money is found for cops. So if you just look
at raw correlations between police and crime, you will find that when
there are more police, there tends to be more crime. That doesn’t
mean, of course, that the police are causing the crime, just as it doesn’t
mean, as some criminologists have argued, that crime will fall if criminals
are released from prison.
To show causality, we need a scenario in which more police are
hired for reasons completely unrelated to rising crime. If, for instance,
police were randomly sprinkled in some cities and not in others, we
could look to see whether crime declines in the cities where the police
happen to land.As it turns out, that exact scenario is often created by vote-hungry
politicians. In the months leading up to Election Day, incumbent
mayors routinely try to lock up the law-and-order vote by hiring more
police—even when the crime rate is standing still. So by comparing
the crime rate in one set of cities that have recently had an election
(and which therefore hired extra police) with another set of cities that
had no election (and therefore no extra police), it’s possible to tease
out the effect of the extra police on crime. The answer: yes indeed, additional
police substantially lower the crime rate.
Again, it may help to look backward and see why crime had risen
so much in the first place. From 1960 to 1985, the number of police
officersfell more than 50 percent relative to the number of crimes. Insome cases, hiring additional police was considered a violation of the
era’s liberal aesthetic; in others, it was simply deemed too expensive.
This 50 percent decline in police translated into a roughly equal decline
in the probability that a given criminal would be caught. Coupled
with the above-cited leniency in the other half of the criminal
justice system, the courtrooms, this decrease in policing created a
strong positive incentive for criminals.
By the 1990s, philosophies—and necessities—had changed. The
policing trend was put in reverse, with wide-scale hiring in cities
across the country. Not only did all those police act as a deterrent, but
they also provided the manpower to imprison criminals who might
have otherwise gone uncaught. The hiring of additional police accounted
for roughly 10 percent of the 1990s crime drop.
But it wasn’t only the number of police that changed in the 1990s;
consider the most commonly cited crime-drop explanation of all:
innovative policing strategies.There was perhaps no more attractive theory than the belief that
smart policing stops crime. It offered a set of bona fide heroes rather
than simply a dearth of villains. This theory rapidly became an article
of faith because it appealed to the factors that, according to John Kenneth
Galbraith, most contribute to the formation of conventional
wisdom: the ease with which an idea may be understood and the degree
to which it affects our personal well-being.
The story played out most dramatically in New York City, where
newly elected mayor Rudolph Giuliani and his handpicked police
commissioner, William Bratton, vowed to fix the city’s desperate
crime situation. Bratton took a novel approach to policing. He ushered
the NYPD into what one senior police official later called “our
Athenian period,” in which new ideas were given weight over calcified
practices. Instead of coddling his precinct commanders, Bratton demanded
accountability. Instead of relying solely on old-fashioned copknow-how, he introduced technological solutions like CompStat, a
computerized method of addressing crime hot spots.
The most compelling new idea that Bratton brought to life
stemmed from the broken window theory, which was conceived by
the criminologists James Q. Wilson and George Kelling. The broken
window theory argues that minor nuisances, if left unchecked, turn
into major nuisances: that is, if someone breaks a window and sees it
isn’t fixed immediately, he gets the signal that it’s all right to break the
rest of the windows and maybe set the building afire too.
So with murder raging all around, Bill Bratton’s cops began to
police the sort of deeds that used to go unpoliced: jumping a subway
turnstile, panhandling too aggressively, urinating in the streets, swabbing
a filthy squeegee across a car’s windshield unless the driver made
an appropriate “donation.”
Most New Yorkers loved this crackdown on its own merit. But
they particularly loved the idea, as stoutly preached by Bratton and
Giuliani, that choking off these small crimes was like choking off the
criminal element’s oxygen supply. Today’s turnstile jumper might easily
be wanted for yesterday’s murder. That junkie peeing in an alley
might have been on his way to a robbery.As violent crime began to fall dramatically, New Yorkers were more
than happy to heap laurels on their operatic, Brooklyn-bred mayor
and his hatchet-faced police chief with the big Boston accent. But
the two strong-willed men weren’t very good at sharing the glory.
Soon after the city’s crime turnaround landed Bratton—and not
Giuliani—on the cover of Time, Bratton was pushed to resign. He
had been police commissioner for just twenty-seven months.
New York City was a clear innovator in police strategies during the
1990s crime drop, and it also enjoyed the greatest decline in crime of
any large American city. Homicide rates fell from 30.7 per 100,000
people in 1990 to 8.4 per 100,000 people in 2000, a change of 73.6policing strategies probably had little effect on this huge decline.
First, the drop in crime in New York began in 1990. By the end of
1993, the rate of property crime and violent crime, including homicides,
had already fallen nearly 20 percent. Rudolph Giuliani, however,
did not become mayor—and install Bratton—until early 1994.
Crime was well on its way down before either man arrived. And it
would continue to fall long after Bratton was bumped from office.
Second, the new police strategies were accompanied by a much
more significant change within the police force: a hiring binge. Between
1991 and 2001, the NYPD grew by 45 percent, more than
three times the national average. As argued above, an increase in the
number of police, regardless of new strategies, has been proven to reduce
crime. By a conservative calculation, this huge expansion of
New York’s police force would be expected to reduce crime in New
York by 18 percent relative to the national average. If you subtract
that 18 percent from New York’s homicide reduction, thereby discounting
the effect of the police-hiring surge, New York no longer
leads the nation with its 73.6 percent drop; it goes straight to the middle
of the pack. Many of those new police were in fact hired by David
Dinkins, the mayor whom Giuliani defeated. Dinkins had been desperate
to secure the law-and-order vote, having known all along that
his opponent would be Giuliani, a former federal prosecutor. (The
two men had run against each other four years earlier as well.) So
those who wish to credit Giuliani with the crime drop may still do so,
for it was his own law-and-order reputation that made Dinkins hire
all those police. In the end, of course, the police increase helpedeveryone—
but it helped Giuliani a lot more than Dinkins.
Most damaging to the claim that New York’s police innovations
radically lowered crime is one simple and often overlooked fact: crime
went down everywhere during the 1990s, not only in New York. Fewother cities tried the kind of strategies that New York did, and certainly
none with the same zeal. But even in Los Angeles, a city notorious
for bad policing, crime fell at about the same rate as it did in New
York once the growth in New York’s police force is accounted for.
It would be churlish to argue that smart policing isn’t a good thing.
Bill Bratton certainly deserves credit for invigorating New York’s police
force. But there is frighteningly little evidence that his strategy
was the crime panacea that he and the media deemed it. The next step
will be to continue measuring the impact of police innovations—in
Los Angeles, for instance, where Bratton himself became police chief
in late 2002. While he duly instituted some of the innovations that
were his hallmark in New York, Bratton announced that his highest
priority was a more basic one: finding the money to hire thousands of
new police officers.
Now to explore another pair of common crime-drop explanations:
Tougher gun laws
Changes in crack and other drug marketsFirst, the guns. Debates on this subject are rarely coolheaded. Gun
advocates believe that gun laws are too strict; opponents believe exactly
the opposite. How can intelligent people view the world so differently?
Because a gun raises a complex set of issues that change
according to one factor: whose hand happens to be holding the gun.
It might be worthwhile to take a step back and ask a rudimentary
question: what is a gun? It’s a tool that can be used to kill someone, of
course, but more significantly, a gun is a great disrupter of the natural
order.
A gun scrambles the outcome of any dispute. Let’s say that a tough
Where Have A l l t h e C r i m i n a l s G o n e?
guy and a not-so-tough guy exchange words in a bar, which leads to a
fight. It’s pretty obvious to the not-so-tough guy that he’ll be beaten,
so why bother fighting? The pecking order remains intact. But if the
not-so-tough guy happens to have a gun, he stands a good chance of
winning. In this scenario, the introduction of a gun may well lead to
more violence.
Now instead of the tough guy and the not-so-tough guy, picture a
high-school girl out for a nighttime stroll when she is suddenly set
upon by a mugger. What if only the mugger is armed? What if only
the girl is armed? What if both are armed? A gun opponent might
argue that the gun has to be kept out of the mugger’s hands in the first
place. A gun advocate might argue that the high-school girl needs to
have a gun to disrupt what has become the natural order: it’s the bad
guys that have the guns. (If the girl scares off the mugger, then the introduction
of a gun in this case may lead to less violence.) Any mugger
with even a little initiative is bound to be armed, for in a country like
the United States, with a thriving black market in guns, anyone can
get hold of one.
There are enough guns in the United States that if you gave one to
every adult, you would run out of adults before you ran out of guns.
Nearly two-thirds of U.S. homicides involve a gun, a far greater fraction
than in other industrialized countries. Our homicide rate is also
much higher than in those countries. It would therefore seem likely
that our homicide rate is so high in part becauseare so easily
available. Research indeed shows this to be true.
But guns are not the whole story. In Switzerland, every adult male
is issued an assault rifle for militia duty and is allowed to keep the gun
at home. On a per capita basis, Switzerland has more firearms than
just about any other country, and yet it is one of the safest places in the
world. In other words, guns do not cause crime. That said, the established
U.S. methods of keeping guns away from the people who docause crime are, at best, feeble. And since a gun—unlike a bag of cocaine
or a car or a pair of pants—lasts pretty much forever, even turning
off the spigot of new guns still leaves an ocean of available ones.
So bearing all this in mind, let’s consider a variety of recent gun initiatives
to see the impact they may have had on crime in the 1990s.
The most famous gun-control law is the Brady Act, passed in
1993, which requires a criminal check and a waiting period before a
person can purchase a handgun. This solution may have seemed appealing
to politicians, but to an economist it doesn’t make much
sense. Why? Because regulation of a legal market is bound to fail
when a healthy black market exists for the same product. With guns
so cheap and so easy to get, the standard criminal has no incentive to
fill out a firearms application at his local gun shop and then wait a
week. The Brady Act, accordingly, has proven to be practically impotent
in lowering crime. (A study of imprisoned felons showed that
even before the Brady Act, only about one-fifth of the criminals had
bought their guns through a licensed dealer.) Various local guncontrol
laws have also failed. Washington, D.C., and Chicago both
instituted handgun bans well before crime began to fall across the
country in the 1990s, and yet those two cities were laggards, not leaders,
in the national reduction in crime.One deterrent that has proven
moderately effective is a stiff increase in prison time for anyone
caught in possession of an illegal gun. But there is plenty of room for
improvement. Not that this is likely, but if the death penalty were
assessed to anyone carrying an illegal gun, and if the penalty were
actually enforced, gun crimes would surely plunge.
Another staple of 1990s crime fighting—and of the evening
news—was the gun buyback. You remember the image: a menacing,
glistening heap of firearms surrounded by the mayor, the police chief,
the neighborhood activists. It made for a nice photo op, but that’s
about as meaningful as a gun buyback gets. The guns that are turnedin tend to be heirlooms or junk. The payoff to the gun seller—usually
$50 or $100, but in one California buyback, three free hours of
psychotherapy—isn’t an adequate incentive for anyone who actually
plans to use his gun. And the number of surrendered guns is no match
for even the number of new guns simultaneously coming to market.
Given the number of handguns in the United States and the number
of homicides each year, the likelihood that a particular gun was used
to kill someone that year is 1 in 10,000. The typical gun buyback
program yields fewer than 1,000 guns—which translates into an expectation
of less than one-tenth of one homicide per buyback. Not
enough, that is, to make even a sliver of impact on the fall of crime.
Then there is an opposite argument—that we need more guns on
the street, but in the hands of the right people (like the high-school
girl above, instead of her mugger). The economist John R. Lott Jr. is
the main champion of this idea. His calling card is the book More
Guns, Less Crime, in which he argues that violent crime has decreased
in areas where law-abiding citizens are allowed to carry concealed
weapons. His theory might be surprising, but it is sensible. If a criminal
thinks his potential victim may be armed, he may be deterred
from committing the crime. Handgun opponents call Lott a pro-gun
ideologue, and Lott let himself become a lightning rod for gun controversy.
He exacerbated his trouble by creating a pseudonym, “Mary
Rosh,” to defend his theory in online debates. Rosh, identifying herself
as a former student of Lott’s, praised her teacher’s intellect, his
evenhandedness, his charisma. “I have to say that he was the best professor
that I ever had,” s/he wrote. “You wouldn’t know that he was a‘right-wing’ ideologue from the class. . . . There were a group of us
students who would try to take any class that he taught. Lott finally
had to tell us that it was best for us to try and take classes from other
professors more to be exposed to other ways of teaching graduate material.”
Then there was the troubling allegation that Lott actually in-vented some of the survey data that support his more-guns/less-crime
theory. Regardless of whether the data were faked, Lott’s admittedly
intriguing hypothesis doesn’t seem to be true. When other scholars
have tried to replicate his results, they found that right-to-carry laws
simply don’t bring down crime.
Consider the next crime-drop explanation: the bursting of the crack
bubble. Crack cocaine was such a potent, addictive drug that a hugely
profitable market had been created practically overnight. True, it was
only the leaders of the crack gangs who were getting rich. But that
only made the street-level dealers all the more desperate to advance.
Many of them were willing to kill their rivals to do so, whether the
rival belonged to the same gang or a different one. There were also gun
battles over valuable drug-selling corners. The typical crack murder
involved one crack dealer shooting another (or two of them, or three)
and not, contrary to conventional wisdom, some bug-eyed crackhead
shooting a shopkeeper over a few dollars. The result was a huge increase
in violent crime. One study found that more than 25 percent of
the homicides in New York City in 1988 were crack-related.The violence associated with crack began to ebb in about 1991.
This has led many people to think that crack itself went away. It
didn’t. Smoking crack remains much more popular today than most
people realize. Nearly 5 percent of all arrests in the United States are
still related to cocaine (as against 6 percent at crack’s peak); nor have
emergency room visits for crack users diminished all that much.
What did go away were the huge profits for selling crack. The price
of cocaine had been falling for years, and it got only cheaper as crack
grew more popular. Dealers began to underprice one another; profits
vanished. The crack bubble burst as dramatically as the Nasdaq bubble
would eventually burst. (Think of the first generation of crackdealers as the Microsoft millionaires; think of the second generation
as Pets.com.) As veteran crack dealers were killed or sent to prison,
younger dealers decided that the smaller profits didn’t justify the risk.
The tournament had lost its allure. It was no longer worth killing
someone to steal their crack turf, and certainly not worth being killed.
So the violence abated. From 1991 to 2001, the homicide rate
among young black men—who were disproportionately represented
among crack dealers—fell 48 percent, compared to 30 percent for
older black men and older white men. (Another minor contributor to
the falling homicide rate is the fact that some crack dealers took to
shooting their enemies in the buttocks rather than murdering them;
this method of violent insult was considered more degrading—and
was obviously less severely punished—than murder.) All told, the
crash of the crack market accounted for roughly 15 percent of the
crime drop of the 1990s—a substantial factor, to be sure, though it
should be noted that crack was responsible for far more than 15 percent
of the crime increase of the 1980s. In other words, the net effect
of crack is still being felt in the form of violent crime, to say nothing
of the miseries the drug itself continues to cause.The final pair of crime-drop explanations concern two demographic
trends. The first one received many media citations: aging of the population.
Until crime fell so drastically, no one talked about this theory at all.
In fact, the “bloodbath” school of criminology was touting exactly the
opposite theory—that an increase in the teenage share of the population
would produce a crop of superpredators who would lay the nation
low. “Just beyond the horizon, there lurks a cloud that the winds
will soon bring over us,” James Q. Wilson wrote in 1995. “Thepopulation
will start getting younger again. . . . Get ready.”But overall, the teenage share of the population wasn’t getting
much bigger. Criminologists like Wilson and James Alan Fox had
badly misread the demographic data. The real population growth in
the 1990s was in fact among the elderly. While this may have been
scary news in terms of Medicare and Social Security, the average
American had little to fear from the growing horde of oldsters. It
shouldn’t be surprising to learn that elderly people are not very criminally
intent; the average sixty-five-year-old is about one-fiftieth as
likely to be arrested as the average teenager. That is what makes this
aging-of-the-population theory of crime reduction so appealingly
tidy: since people mellow out as they get older, more older people
must lead to less crime. But a thorough look at the data reveals that
the graying of America did nothing to bring down crime in the 1990s.
Demographic change is too slow and subtle a process—you don’t
graduate from teenage hoodlum to senior citizen in just a few years—
to even begin to explain the suddenness of the crime decline.
There was another demographic change, however, unforeseen and
long-gestating, that did drastically reduce crime in the 1990s.Think back for a moment to Romania in 1966. Suddenly and
without warning, NicolaeCeaus¸escu declared abortion illegal. The
children born in the wake of the abortion ban were much more likely
to become criminals than children born earlier. Why was that? Studies
in other parts of Eastern Europe and in Scandinavia from the
1930s through the 1960s reveal a similar trend. In most of these cases,
abortion was not forbidden outright, but a woman had to receive permission
from a judge in order to obtain one. Researchers found that
in the instances where the woman was denied an abortion, she often
resented her baby and failed to provide it with a good home. Even
when controlling for the income, age, education, and health of the
mother, the researchers found that these children too were more likely
to become criminals.The United States, meanwhile, has had a different abortion history
than Europe. In the early days of the nation, it was permissible to have
an abortion prior to “quickening”—that is, when the first movements
of the fetus could be felt, usually around the sixteenth to eighteenth
week of pregnancy. In 1828, New York became the first state to restrict
abortion; by 1900 it had been made illegal throughout the
country. Abortion in the twentieth century was often dangerous and
usually expensive. Fewer poor women, therefore, had abortions. They
also had less access to birth control. What they did have, accordingly,
was a lot more babies.
In the late 1960s, several states began to allow abortion under extreme
circumstances: rape, incest, or danger to the mother. By 1970
five states had made abortion entirely legal and broadly available:
New York, California, Washington, Alaska, and Hawaii. On January
22, 1973, legalized abortion was suddenly extended to the entire
country with the U.S. Supreme Court’s ruling in Roe v. Wade. The
majority opinion, written by Justice Harry Blackmun, spoke specifically
to the would-be mother’s predicament:The detriment that the State would impose upon the pregnant
woman by denying this choice altogether is apparent. . . .
Maternity, or additional offspring, may force upon the woman
a distressful life and future. Psychological harm may be imminent.
Mental and physical health may be taxed by child care.
There is also the distress, for all concerned, associated with the
unwanted child, and there is the problem of bringing a child
into a family already unable, psychologically and otherwise, to
care for it.
The Supreme Court gave voice to what the mothers in Romania
and Scandinavia—and elsewhere—had long known: when a womandoes not want to have a child, she usually has good reason. She may be
unmarried or in a bad marriage. She may consider herself too poor to
raise a child. She may think her life is too unstable or unhappy, or she
may think that her drinking or drug use will damage the baby’s
health. She may believe that she is too young or hasn’t yet received
enough education. She may want a child badly but in a few years, not
now. For any of a hundred reasons, she may feel that she cannot provide
a home environment that is conducive to raising a healthy and
productive child.
In the first year after Roe v. Wade, some 750,000 women had abortions
in the United States (representing one abortion for every 4 live
births). By 1980 the number of abortions reached 1.6 million (one
for every 2.25 live births), where it leveled off. In a country of 225
million people, 1.6 million abortions per year—one for every 140
Americans—may not have seemed so dramatic. In the first year after
NicolaeCeaus¸escu’s death, when abortion was reinstated in Romania,
there was one abortion for every twenty-two Romanians. But still: 1.6
million American women a year who got pregnant were suddenly not
having those babies.Before Roe v. Wade, it was predominantly the daughters of middleor
upper-class families who could arrange and afford a safe illegal
abortion. Now, instead of an illegal procedure that might cost $500,
any woman could easily obtain an abortion, often for less than $100.
What sort of woman was most likely to take advantage of Roe
v. Wade? Very often she was unmarried or in her teens or poor, and
sometimes all three. What sort of future might her child have had?
One study has shown that the typical child who went unborn in the
earliest years of legalized abortion would have been 50 percent more
likely than average to live in poverty; he would have also been 60 percent
more likely to grow up with just one parent. These two factors—
childhood poverty and a single-parent household—are among the
strongest predictors that a child will have a criminal future. Growingup in a single-parent home roughly doubles a child’s propensity to
commit crime. So does having a teenage mother. Another study has
shown that low maternal education is the single most powerful factor
leading to criminality.
In other words, the very factors that drove millions of American
women to have an abortion also seemed to predict that their children,
had they been born, would have led unhappy and possibly criminal
lives.
To be sure, the legalization of abortion in the United States had
myriad consequences. Infanticide fell dramatically. So did shotgun
marriages, as well as the number of babies put up for adoption (which
has led to the boom in the adoption of foreign babies). Conceptions
rose by nearly 30 percent, but births actually fell by 6 percent, indicating
that many women were using abortion as a method of birth
control, a crude and drastic sort of insurance policyPerhaps the most dramatic effect of legalized abortion, however,
and one that would take years to reveal itself, was its impact on crime.
In the early 1990s, just as the first cohort of children born after Roe
v. Wade was hitting its late teen years—the years during which young
men enter their criminal prime—the rate of crime began to fall. What
this cohort was missing, of course, were the children who stood the
greatest chance of becoming criminals. And the crime rate continued
to fall as an entire generation came of age minus the children whose
mothers had not wanted to bring a child into the world. Legalized
abortion led to less unwantedness; unwantedness leads to high crime;
legalized abortion, therefore, led to less crime.
This theory is bound to provoke a variety of reactions, ranging
from disbelief to revulsion, and a variety of objections, ranging from
the quotidian to the moral. The likeliest first objection is the most
straightforward one: is the theory true? Perhaps abortion and crime
are merely correlated and not causal.
It may be more comforting to believe what the newspapers say,that the drop in crime was due to brilliant policing and clever gun
control and a surging economy. We have evolved with a tendency to
link causality to things we can touch or feel, not to some distant or
difficult phenomenon. We believe especially in near-term causes: a
snake bites your friend, he screams with pain, and he dies. The
snakebite, you conclude, must have killed him. Most of the time,
such a reckoning is correct. But when it comes to cause and effect,
there is often a trap in such open-and-shut thinking. We smirk now
when we think of ancient cultures that embraced faulty causes—the
warriors who believed, for instance, that it was their raping of a virgin
that brought them victory on the battlefield. But we too embrace
faulty causes, usually at the urging of an expert proclaiming a truth in
which he has a vested interest.
How, then, can we tell if the abortion-crime link is a case of causality
rather than simply correlation?One way to test the effect of abortion on crime would be to measure
crime data in the five states where abortion was made legal before
the Supreme Court extended abortion rights to the rest of the country.
In New York, California, Washington, Alaska, and Hawaii, a
woman had been able to obtain a legal abortion for at least two years
beforeRoe v. Wade. And indeed, those early-legalizing states saw crime
begin to fall earlier than the other forty-five states and the District of
Columbia. Between 1988 and 1994, violent crime in the earlylegalizing
states fell 13 percent compared to the other states; between
1994 and 1997, their murder rates fell 23 percent more than those of
the other states.
But what if those early legalizers simply got lucky? What else might
we look for in the data to establish an abortion-crime link?
One factor to look for would be a correlation between each state’s
abortion rate and its crime rate. Sure enough, the states with the highest
abortion rates in the 1970s experienced the greatest crime drops inthe 1990s, while states with low abortion rates experienced smaller
crime drops. (This correlation exists even when controlling for a variety
of factors that influence crime: a state’s level of incarceration,
number of police, and its economic situation.) Since 1985, states with
high abortion rates have experienced a roughly 30 percent drop in
crime relative to low-abortion states. (New York City had high abortion
ratesand lay within an early-legalizing state, a pair of facts that
further dampen the claim that innovative policing caused the crime
drop.) Moreover, there was no link between a given state’s abortion
rate and its crime rate before the late 1980s—when the first cohort affected
by legalized abortion was reaching its criminal prime—which
is yet another indication that Roe v. Wade was indeed the event that
tippedthecrimescale.
Date: 2015-04-20; view: 964
|