![]() CATEGORIES: BiologyChemistryConstructionCultureEcologyEconomyElectronicsFinanceGeographyHistoryInformaticsLawMathematicsMechanicsMedicineOtherPedagogyPhilosophyPhysicsPolicyPsychologySociologySportTourism |
Borrowing From the Central BankIn other words borrowing from the central bank is called “monetizing” the deficit. Because this method always leads to the growth of monetary base and of money supply, it is often referred to as just “printing money”. As can readily be seen from equation (2), here increase in the high-powered money is the source of financing budget deficit. Monetization occurs (i) when the central bank directly finances budget deficit by lending funds needed to pay government bills; or (ii) when the central bank purchases government debt at the time of issuance or later in the course of open market operations. If the central bank just lends funds or purchases newly issued government debt, it simply pushes up the stock of high-powered money. It may also be the case that the government first borrows from public or from commercial banking system. However, if the central bank then intervenes and either buys out the debt from the public by means of open market operations or accommodates additional demand for liquidity from banking system, the equivalent amount of reserves gets injected into the economy as if the government originally borrowed from the central bank. In either case budget deficit (DEF) is financed, as can be seen from equation above, by increases in high-powered money. Let us now assume that the government for some reasons can borrow only from the central bank (it has lost the public’s confidence and foreign exchange reserves are near the critical level). Then our budget deficit financing equation will look like:
If we follow the assumptions of Sachs and Larrain (1993) that Purchasing Power Parity (PPP), as well as quantity theory of money hold, then, under a fixed exchange rate regime, one reaches the following conclusion: even if government tries to borrow from the central bank, and it starts printing money, the bank in effect is running down already depleted foreign exchange reserves, because it has to intervene in foreign exchange market to maintain the fixed exchange rate. This in turn will lead to a reversal of the money supply increase, i.e. ultimately Under a floating exchange rate regime the outcome is different. Let’s now distinguish the nominal (DEF) from real (DEFr) value of budget deficit so that In other words, the real value of the deficit is now equal to the real value of the change in money supply. The budget deficit in such a situation is said to be financed by collecting seigniorage. In Dornbusch and Fischer’s words (1998), seigniorage refers to “the government’s ability to raise revenue through its right to create money”. The amount of seigniorage (S) is then given by the expression: Interestingly, the amount of seigniorage can usefully be decomposed into the “pure seigniorage” and “inflation tax” part. It can be shown[4] that:
In the words of Dornbusch and Fischer (1998), “inflation acts just like a tax because people are forced to spend less than their income and pay the difference to the government in exchange for extra money. The government thus can spend more resources, and the public less, just as if the government had raised taxes to finance extra spending”. When government finances a deficit by printing money, there are good reasons to believe that the public seeks to maintain real balances so as to offset the effects of inflation. The public therefore chooses to hold more and more nominal money from period to period, so as to keep real balances and thus purchasing power constant in the long run. If this is the case, then Thus, we may conclude that under a pure floating exchange rate regime, budget deficit ends up in inflation and, as shown above, the size of the deficit and inflation rate are very closely connected. According to the formula, higher deficits entail higher inflation rates (Sachs and Larrain, 1993). In passing we should note the implication that macroeconomic theory derives about financing a budget deficit through inflation tax: a sustained increase in money growth and in inflation ultimately leads to a reduction in the real money stock (Dornbusch and Fischer 1998). With respect to transition economies, the rationale behind such an implication may be that public adjusts to the higher inflation by switching from heavily taxed domestic currency to a different hard and stable currency (e.g. U.S. dollar). So far we have basically considered the most essential mechanisms of financing a budget deficit. However, one additional strong statement that seems appropriate and relevant here should be made. A sustained inflation may stem only from a persistent rather than a temporary budget deficit that is eventually financed by printing money rather than by borrowing from public (Mishkin, 2000). Date: 2015-02-28; view: 1187
|